No Stupid Questions - 67. How Can You Escape Binary Thinking?
Episode Date: September 19, 2021Also: why is it so satisfying to find a bargain? ...
Transcript
Discussion (0)
You are blowing my tiny mind right now.
I'm Angela Duckworth.
I'm Stephen Dubner.
And you're listening to No Stupid Questions.
Today on the show, how can you become less of a binary thinker?
My way is the right way.
Also, why does bargain hunting bring people so much joy?
I was, as a young woman, a great coupon clipper.
Angie, I want to be less of a binary thinker, and I wonder if you can help me.
Well, Stephen, you know, there are two kinds of people. People who like binary thinking.
Just kidding. I couldn't resist.
Here's my problem. I'm not sure whether this is me personally, whether this is the human condition, or whether it's the human condition in the modern era, you know, society and politics and media being what they are in this early 21st century, I guess it is.
But I feel that the confluence of all these forces is constantly herding me into yes or no, black
or white, all or nothing choices.
You know, you can't belong to political movement X unless you subscribe to all 20 of its tenets
and precisely zero of the other movement's 20 tenets, for example.
Now, my brain and even my soul know that the world should not work that way,
that there's so much more nuance and variation to how life should unfold, but it's hard to not
veer toward binary thinking. So how can I and everyone get better at that?
Well, you're not alone. It's salient with politics these days, especially in the United States, that you're, you know, all the way on one side, all the way on the other.
It doesn't seem to be a lot of people in the middle ground, not a lot of room or permission even to be a moderate.
But it's actually much more fundamental.
Cognitive scientists have been documenting just how systematic the distortion is when we try to summarize evidence and we
binarize, we create categories of what is effectively continuous data.
Oh, that's so interesting.
Can you give an example?
There was a study in Psych Science and the title of this paper is The Binary Bias.
Oh, it's a thing.
Yeah, plus alliteration.
is the binary bias.
Oh, it's a thing.
Yeah, plus alliteration.
Binary bias, a systematic distortion in the integration of information.
And these scientists run a variety of paradigms
that essentially say that when people are looking at data
and visualizations of data, et cetera,
that they tend to be biased toward this extremity
that's in their own minds, but it's not really in the data.
So we tend to make categories of continuous data. And there are other studies documenting
this tendency. When I thought about this without being a scientist who studies this directly,
I thought there must be a functional purpose to binarizing, like so many biases.
Right. That animal will kill me and that one won't.
Well, exactly. Life is about action and action is either or.
But I feel like you're telling me now that we take in information
only for the purpose of acting upon it in some kind of finite, irreversible way.
Yeah.
No.
True.
No. True. No.
Come on.
All information processing is so that you can make decisions to act in one way or another.
I mean, you could make the argument that there's learning for learning's sake.
But then if you just keep asking the question, why is it important to learn that?
And then why is that important?
You do, I think, eventually get to the fundamental truth of existence, which is that you have to survive and you have to make decisions to act in one way or act in another.
You are blowing my tiny mind right now. probably in one out of every four conversations we have, which is everything we do can, of course,
be explained by some evolutionary condition.
The classic example is you're walking across the savannah,
Angie, and you hear a rustle in the grass.
Do you run?
Do you not run?
The answer is, of course you run,
because that rustle could be the wind,
but if it's a saber-toothed tiger,
then Angie exists no more. That's a classic all or nothing. But I feel like we're kind of running
that old software on much better hardware or that our hardware should be much better.
But you're telling me that we have this binary bias because life is all about action. And if you choose the
wrong action, you die. And that just feels a little harsh. I want to highlight that I am not
one of these cognitive scientists who studies categorical thinking. It just occurred to me
that one of the reasons why, maybe the reason why we might do this is because action is binary. I
mean, let's take the example of going to the doctor's office.
Doctors are going to put you in a category of either you need this medication or not. You need to do physical therapy or not. When the underlying statistic, your blood pressure, your lipid levels,
whatever it is, must be continuous. And if you read medical journals, there is a lot of
categorizing. Like, what can we say about people who are insulin dependent? And I always thought, well, there's a continuum. to either prescribe you something or not. They have
to give you directions. And so that just illustrates how much of life is about making decisions to take
actions and the actions themselves are categorical. You don't make a 40% right turn and a 60% left
turn. You either turn right or you turn left. Okay, point taken, especially on the medical
example. But let me offer a slightly nuanced version,
which is there's the wait and see option.
There's the this and that option.
There's the low dose option.
In other words, yes, I get that categorization, but I think that most medical doctors that
I know, and I'm thinking now, especially of Bapu Jena, who is an MD and economist,
which makes him a double threat.
Oh, isn't he the host of your new podcast?
He is. Good plug for the network. Freakonomics MD, it's called. So one of the kinds of things
that Bapu wrestles with is how much treatment is good treatment and what is excess treatment
all about and what's the difference between the false positive and the false negative.
I would argue that most of the best doctors and the false negative? I would argue that most
of the best doctors who are taking this question seriously would say that they probably are forced
to do too much binary or even categorical thinking because diagnosing is hard. Even at this late
date, there's a lot of science, but there's a lot of art to it and there's a lot of uncertainty to it. I understand that you're saying binary thinking and binary action are often the most obvious and
maybe the most pressing choice, but I would like to live in a world where there was more
consideration of the spectrum of choices. That's all I'm saying. And you're telling me I'm mostly
wrong. No, I am not telling you you're mostly wrong. One of my life goals is to help people not binarize so much. Here's something from my own field, psychology. When you take psychopathology, this is the first graduate course if you're going to become a clinical psychologist, a real psychologist, as I like to say, you know, somebody who does therapy.
therapy. We've all heard of mental illnesses like schizophrenia, manic depression. And when I started out in this course, I thought, well, I'll learn about these categories of mental illness
and what puts somebody in that category. And it never occurred to me that, for example,
schizophrenia could be really just a continuum, that you could be severely schizophrenic,
really just a continuum, that you could be severely schizophrenic, moderately schizophrenic,
and then not at all. It turns out that for almost everything that psychologists study,
including these things that seem categorical, that they really are continuous. And you do have to, at the end of the day, either allocate a therapist to this person or not based on a diagnosis.
allocate a therapist to this person or not based on a diagnosis. But if we all knew that the underlying phenomena were continuous for most things in psychology and maybe most things in
life, that would be, I think, in advance. Okay, so you don't disagree with me as much as I was
saying that you disagree with me. Let me agree with you a little bit more than I sounded like
I was agreeing with you before, which is to say, plainly, there is value in binary thinking. I mean, literally, the fundamental
building block, as far as I understand it, of computing is the bit, which is short for binary
digit, which is either a zero or one. And the reason that's useful for computers is it makes it
easier to do huge computation, which means you require less circuitry, less cooling,
things can be smaller, Things can be cheaper.
It's a massive data compression.
Yeah.
So it is a heuristic for computers.
But, you know, I'd like to think maybe this is one way we can be better than computers,
is not having to compress.
On the other hand, I am a fan of what I believe is called generally categorical thinking.
I just want more categories than two.
I was reading, there's a piece here I see from the Harvard Business Review called the dangers of categorical thinking. Categorical thinking, it says, can be dangerous in four important ways.
Number one, it can lead you to compress the members of a category, treating them as if they
were more alike than they are. Number two, it can amplify differences between members of a category, treating them as if they were more alike than they are. Number two, it can amplify differences between members of different categories. Number three, you can
discriminate favoring certain categories over others. And number four, you can fossilize
treating the categorical structure you've imposed as if it were static. That's the one that really
gets me. And so when I read that, I think, you know what? Yeah, they've got my number. The authors, I should say, are Bart DeLange and Philip Fernbach. And I feel what they're expressing is in acknowledging that there is a danger or at least some kind of downside to categorical thinking, it encouraged us to think more fluidly across categories and to consider every person, every encounter, every interaction, every choice,
one that is, as you've said, on a spectrum. At the end of the day, when we make the decision,
it's not a one or a zero. It's not a yes or no. The decision could be,
I'm going to try this for a little while and keep a really close eye on it and see if it seems to be
working. And if it's not, I'm going to try something different. That's all I'm talking about in wanting to be less binary. Does that make any sense?
It makes total sense. And I think it's quite reasonable to say that whatever these tendencies
are, we can understand why we have them and how in some sense or in certain contexts, it could be
good, useful, adaptive. But even just understanding that helps you move ahead and say, okay, well,
where are the circumstances where that's not helpful? And I absolutely think that we should
in 2021, 2022 and beyond be able to say, look, we have enough bandwidth that we can accommodate more
than two categories for a given issue and understand that even when we have to make decisions, what we're doing is making those decisions that are binary on continuous data.
Let me back up because we did talk a little bit about the political divide. It may be
that the political system in our country especially is what exhibits this binary
thinking and executes it so fully that it has spilled over into the broader culture.
You mean getting us to be even more binary?
Yeah. It's pretty easy to look at the way someone dresses these days or to look at the
kind of car they drive and feel you know a lot about their beliefs. And that's remarkable that
we have allowed ourselves to be so binarily divided. On the other hand, I did find one piece of encouraging news.
Gallup found that 62% of Americans currently say a third political party is needed. Now,
I don't know if that's historically high, but that strikes me as high in the moment.
Separately, there was a recent survey of about 2,500 young Americans, 18 to 29 years old. This
was a survey by the Institute of Politics at
Harvard. And it found that 76% of them agreed with the following statement, quote, we need
more open-mindedness in politics. And only 4% of the respondents disagreed with that statement.
And then the other people were what?
Somewhere in the middle.
It's a continuum after all.
It is a continuum after all. Now, when I read the numbers from the young people, I think, wow, that's a really good sign in that most young people, 83% of the young Democrats and 70% of the young Republicans agreed that more interested in being open-minded, whereas
when we get older, we get calcified and sclerotic and cranky and say, my way is the right way. So,
I don't know just how hopeful to be about that data. Well, we should study this, whether binary
thinking has led to or at least contributed massively to the polarization of politics. That's certainly
possible. Does the direction of causality go the other way? And also what to do about it,
because I think young people despair a little bit at the kind of false polarization that's going on.
I mean, I'm not that young, but I count myself among them.
Speaking of what to do about it, I'm curious if you can tell me anything about what I've seen
called dialectical behavior therapy.
Dialectical behavior therapy is an adaptation of cognitive behavioral therapy. And cognitive
behavioral therapy is the dominant form of psychotherapy over the last 50 years. And that's
all about arguing yourself out of the irrational thoughts that lead to dysfunctional levels of emotion like severe
anxiety or depression. And then dialectical behavioral therapy grew out of the treatment
approach for people with borderline personality disorder. And actually, if you look under the hood
of dialectical behavioral therapy, a lot of it looks like cognitive behavioral therapy, but I
believe that the term dialectical comes from the idea that there are
these apparent paradoxes that you have to live with. Like, you have to understand that you're
going to suffer, but you also have to not just give in to your suffering and wallow in it.
But the point of most of therapy, including dialectical behavioral therapy, but also
cognitive behavioral therapy, is for many, many people to get out of black and white thinking.
It's not just people who have borderline personality disorder. So many students take a
test and they get like a C minus and it's like, oh, the world is over. I'm an idiot. You know,
my husband forgot to call me back. He doesn't love me.
Now, that could be true, just to say that should be considered in the spectrum.
Thank you, Stephen, for putting that.
My pleasure.
Now we know why you're not a therapist.
Thank you, Stephen, for putting that.
My pleasure.
Now we know why you're not a therapist.
Really, if you're the sort of nerd who listens to no stupid questions, maybe you can take from this.
The next time I catch myself doing all or none extremist thinking, I'm going to remember that there is this binary bias and I should try to work against it.
How would this actually work in therapy?
So if you come into a therapist's office and you have some kind of black and white exclamation,
like I'm a total failure, what your therapist might ask you to do is to play out in pretty vivid detail first, what it would look like if everything they said was true.
Like, just give me the extreme worst case scenario.
And then you ask them, okay, now let's do the opposite.
Let's flip that on its head.
And as improbable as you think, like just give me the best case scenario.
Then you've got these two extremes.
When you say now I want you to paint me the most likely scenario.
And what you've done is help the person basically expand their mental set
to both extremes, not just the one that they were dwelling on. And you naturally think that the most
likely thing is going to be somewhere in between the poles. And that is a series of questions that
I've actually tried to employ when the rare occasion happens that I slip into this kind of
extreme black, white, catastrophic thinking. it helps me get out of it.
What I like about this notion is it would lead me to be more purely curious about the
world and do a better job of learning more during my work and during my personal life
and less judging, less knee-jerk binary categorization.
And less judging, less knee-jerk binary categorization. That's what I'm after because I find that the binary thinkers in my life are, I'll be honest, the least interesting people.
And the least happy. myself out of my potentially cranky future and into a smooth, slick world where life is a spectrum that's got all the colors of the rainbow and I can just flip from yellow to indigo and back and
forth. That's all I'm asking for. It'll be like the Crayola box. There's blue, green, but there's
also green, blue. Bert Sienna. Bert Sienna.
Old's the littlest crayon because it was so good, especially for tree trunks.
Still to come on No Stupid Questions,
Stephen and Angela discuss the true value of a discount.
So what that you saved $45 on a dress that you probably didn't want anyway. Steven, I got an email the other day from my sister, Annette.
Oh, Annette. She's a doctor of some sort?
Not only a doctor, not only my sister, but a huge fan of this very podcast.
And I think we've actually answered one of her questions before.
This is going to be number two.
So does she get a mug?
She gets a mug and she gets a hug from her sister.
Okay, here's her email.
And maybe what some people call cheap
is how much happiness you derive from transactional utility.
Like you found a dress you love and it was 80% off
and you got it for $9.99. But in the big picture, that amount of money should be inconsequential to you. And I thought to myself, she's asking the question of her very identity because there is no cheaper person on the planet Earth than my sister Annette.
And she would consider that a compliment coming from her sister, I assume?
You're not insulting her.
She would consider that a compliment, I think,
although she obviously wants some vindication here.
And I don't think Annette has ever bought anything for $9.99.
I'm not exaggerating.
On eBay, if she can't get a dress for $4.99, she won't get the dress.
Wow.
So I want to talk about this.
Do you know anything about transactional utility?
I wondered, since you have such a longtime friendship with people like Steve Levitt,
whether you already know about this.
I do know about transactional utility, and I do know about it from an economist at the
University of Chicago, but not Steve Levitt, from Richard Thaler, who you know as well.
Thaler, for those who don't know, is a kind of
special breed of economist in that he considered himself a not very good or promising academic
economist in the early part of his career. And he pursued a pair of psychologists
whose names are Danny Kahneman and Amos Tversky, who we've mentioned many times on the show. And
you know Danny Kahneman well. Amos Tversky was Danny's brilliant partner who died young in the
1990s. And Thaler was the young economist who processed a lot of this decision
making psychological research and applied his understanding of economics to it and turned it
into what we think of as behavioral economics. So transactional utility is meant to describe
the pleasure you get from the perceived value of what you paid versus what you expected to pay. I can see that making
someone very happy. On the other hand, it could also make you suspicious in a different setting,
right? Like, what's wrong with this thing? I get utility from knowing that I paid less than
someone asked for it, but is there something wrong with it? For instance, you know, not does this dress make me look fat, but does this dress make
me look cheap?
That would be theoretically the downside.
Or like a rube, right?
Did I overpay for this dress?
Exactly.
But I will say this.
There's a fair amount of evidence from Thaler and many other economists who've done experimental
research that this thing that we call transactional
utility is real and that it's fairly large. So I'll give you one example. In 2012, the department
store chain JCPenney announced a new policy. I'm reading here from a Time magazine article from
2012. Fake prices inflated big time to make markdowns seem more tempting would disappear from JCPenney.
So basically, JCPenney is saying to their customers, hey, listen, we do this charade
and you seem to enjoy it enough that you're supporting our store. We're successful.
But you know, why do we have a posted list price and then constantly saying markdown 40% off. So you know what? Let's just
do away with that to be replaced with what they were calling a fair and square structure in which
original prices started at least 40% lower to begin with. So what do you think happened?
Well, if I expand upon my sister's experience, they would sell less with the fair and square
pricing, even though it was more transparent. And maybe in some ways you could argue it should be more attractive because people
will not have this feeling of being deceived. But I'm guessing that if people are anything like
Annette Lee, they would have bought fewer things at JCPenney.
You are exactly right. JCPenney sales plummeted, the stock price plummeted. So the charade,
it turns out, is very attractive.
Customers weren't attracted to JCPenney simply because of low prices. They were attracted to
bargains that they got through markdowns and coupons. And then if you go looking at the
research on coupon use, for instance, I'm looking at something from a market research firm called
eMarketer. This is from just a few years ago, 2018.
And they were trying to find out how important coupons and discounts are for different age
groups.
And these are digital purchases.
They found that for the age group 18 to 29, around 82% of the respondents said that it
was very important or important to use a coupon or a discount.
And that number gradually falls as you get older.
People who are 60 and older, only 65% say it's very important.
But still two out of three, right?
Yeah. And also we should say this, I'm guessing, does not factor in at all price sensitivity.
I was going to say, we just have more money.
I remember not having any money. Now I have money. But that said, it may suggest that if indeed these younger people
are more expectant of being able to tag on that coupon, I mean, look, there's a massive
digital industry built around this very concept. It may suggest that over time, as people who are digital natives
get older, that they're going to expect a discount. So, the world will be turning into
Annette Lee, in other words. But I think this whole notion of what your sister is talking about
speaks to something beyond just cognitive biases. I think it says a lot about different cultures,
different families, and different home economics within lot about different cultures, different families,
and different home economics within families. So tell me this, was bargain shopping part of
the family system in the Lee family growing up? I cannot fully account for my sister's cheapness.
I can partially account for her pathological frugality. I mean, she takes it to Olympic sport levels.
I can only offer this. My parents had immigrated from China, and they were never really, really
poor, but they were really, really frugal. Just the other day, my sister and I were remembering
how we would go to the movie theater, and after the movie was over, we would just try to
make it seem like we were there for the second showing. And then we would go for even a third.
And she reminded me that we did that in part because my dad never turned the air conditioning
on. And when you live in southern New Jersey and it's July and your house is 95 degrees,
it's a lot better to be in a movie theater, even if you're breaking the rules to do it. My dad in particular was really cheap. When we went to restaurants,
you know, we rarely did. But when we did go out to eat, it was a given that we would just be
ordering the cheapest entree. So she grew up like that and I grew up like that. But I think the
amount of joy that my sister gets from getting, you know...
Is not related to the family system necessarily.
I mean, come on. So what that you saved $45 on a dress that you probably didn't want anyway,
but she gets so much transaction utility, it starts to be a little bit absurd. By the way,
she's a doctor. She can afford dresses that are more than
$4.99. I do think it is a fine line between transactional utility and extreme frugality
that becomes counterproductive. So when I was a kid, forget about picking the cheapest entree
at the restaurants. We didn't go to restaurants, in part because we lived in the middle of nowhere and there were none, in part because there were many, many children. And also, we just didn't
have any money. Yeah, many children, not a lot of money, rural. Right. So, we made and grew as much
as was possible. Then for the things you had to buy, you tried to spend as little as you could.
One thing that I remember from when I was pretty little being really frustrated at was gasoline.
that I remember from when I was pretty little being really frustrated at was gasoline. My mom would never buy gas at the one tiny little village store in our closest village. As you got closer to
the big city of Schenectady, the gas got a little bit cheaper. But sometimes she would drive 10
miles out of the way to save 25 or 50 cents. And I'm thinking, even as a kid, forget about,
Ma, the cost of the gas that you're burning to get there. But what about the time? And what about
the added risk of a car crash? You're driving all these extra miles. And my mother was also
an extreme couponer. And again, I respect it because she had to be. She had me doing a lot of couponing. There's the clipping,
there's the sorting, there's the culling. The planning. Plus they keep expiring the damn things.
One of my tasks was to sit down with the huge folder, like an accordion folder of coupons
divided into different categories and go through them and remove the expired ones.
divided into different categories and go through them and remove the expired ones.
And I remember thinking then, I would much rather be spending this time doing something that would make me enough money so that I don't have to coupon.
You know, there's the time money trade-off, which is a huge piece of this, because many
people would think that, well, I could spend more time trying to pursue something cheaper,
but what's the shadow price of that time? What's the opportunity cost of that time?
That is actually what turned me off of coupons. I was, as a young woman, a great coupon clipper.
I would, you know, think ahead to the menu that I would make so that I could use this dollar
box of ranzoni pasta that was only because I happened to clip the coupon. And at some point,
I realized that I should actually spend time doing, well, nearly anything else. And so there's
transaction costs, there's transaction utility. But when I got this email from my sister, it
actually spurred another memory. And I think this completes the picture a little bit. So my advisor
in graduate school, as you know, was Marty Seligman.
And Marty told me the story that I think he has since also written about.
But when he was an undergraduate, he was in a lab where the professor had a pet that was a South American lizard.
Not for research. This was an actual pet.
No, I guess there were the animals that had to work.
And then there was this lizard that just got to roam around and that people would take care of.
And when Marty joins the slab, the crisis is that the lizard is dying because it's not eating.
The lizard was recently gifted to this professor.
And as Marty tells a story, they tried everything.
They tried every kind of bug. They tried every kind of fruit combination. They were looking up fruits from South America and they were trying to give it the native fruit. And still the lizard was not supposed to eat the sandwich. It was actually for a human being.
And casually, the professor puts the newspaper on top of the sandwich, probably by accident.
And what happens is the lizard immediately goes into hunting mode and then shreds the newspaper, gets through to the sandwich, and eats the whole thing.
paper, gets through to the sandwich, and eats the whole thing. And Marty took from this the lesson that in life, there's not just success, but the process of getting there. Like life isn't just
the sandwich itself, but the thrill of it. The thrill of the hunt.
And I do think there's something about how in life, there's the dress you buy,
there's the thing you get, but there's the cost of getting there. And then there's the dress you buy, there's the thing you get, but there's the cost of getting there,
and then there's the utility of getting there. It also makes me wonder what the endowment effect
is like for an object that you got a good deal on versus one that you feel you paid either market
price or even maybe more than market price, right? Do you want to expound on what the endowment
effect is for the people who haven't heard of it? Yeah, so the endowment effect says that we endow more value, we assign more value to something that we have.
When we humans have something that we have attained ourselves, whether we've hunted it down like the lizard or not, then we assign a higher value to it than something very similar that someone else has. And so now I'm wondering,
let's say you buy three Xs, three dresses, three books, three whatever they are, and one of them
you got at a great bargain, one of them you paid kind of market price, and the other you hunted it
down and paid above market price. You had to really work for it. I am curious to know what
that endowment effect does to your feeling about those three objects
in the long run.
One might think that the more expensive one would remain more valuable, but I could also
imagine that the one that you somehow scooped up much cheaper may feel even more valuable
given this transactional utility that we're talking about and the difference between perceived
value and real value.
that we're talking about and the difference between perceived value and real value.
So I get some ridiculous deal on a Lululemon workout shirt that's usually $120.
I sound like I'm exaggerating, but for those of you who know Lululemon, you know sadly I'm not.
And I'm like, ooh, look at me, total bargain.
And now, you know, the opportunity comes for me to sell it, I guess.
Well, forget about even selling it. Imagine how you're thinking about it as you continue to own it. That's really what I'm asking, because here's the other thing that's key here. There's also some
signaling going on because you might wear that Lululemon shirt to a yoga class where other people
see it and they know what a Lululemon shirt is and they know what it would cost, but you didn't pay that. So what does that do to your psyche?
I think for me in particular, I'm not saying that my sister would feel this way.
Well, mostly I wouldn't care, but if I cared at all, I don't know if I would prefer that they
thought I paid full price. Right, because then they might take you for like a brand name sucker.
There's also the, you know, like, yay, I did the smartest
thing. I don't know about that. I'm pretty sure nobody studied that. This transaction utility
stuff goes all the way back to early Thaler writing, but there's not a boatload of empirical
research on it. I know that there are many people who feel a different relationship between the
object they have or the object they make even
and money. I've been doing some interviews for Freakonomics Radio lately of artists and art
dealers and museum curators and so on because I find the art market incredibly interesting and
incredibly opaque and incredibly expensive. And I was interviewing one artist who is very successful. His work is
collected in the best museums. He puts on exhibits at amazing cultural institutions and so on.
And yet he couldn't buy his own art at auction. And then I interviewed an art dealer and an art
advisor. And she loves the art of this particular artist. And she wants to own
some work that she can't afford because it's in the, let's say, tens of millions of dollars.
And I think she wants to own it in part simply because it is very, very, very expensive. I'm
sure she loves it, but there's something about the value of it that totally changes the perception.
So, if there is, let's
say, a Basquiat or a Rothko that would sell for $20 million and then a similar painting that would
sell for $20, does she really love it a million times more? That's the kind of question that I
think about when your sister asks about buying that dress.
Well, the point that I think this transaction utility
question makes is really the reason why Thaler got the Nobel Prize, which is that
econs, as he likes to call them, the rational, it only matters what the value is of the good
or service, etc., are unlike humans who have feelings, who make decisions that seem irrational
according to
pure economic theory, that there are other things to factor in. It's a lot more complicated.
And this idea of transaction utility, that there is some amount of happiness or unhappiness
that a human derives from buying a dress or getting a deal on a car that have nothing to do
with the actual dress of the car. For those of you who wondered, like, why the heck did he win the Nobel Prize for his work? It is for giving a more accurate
picture of human decision making. And you know what I would say about my sister's email,
about this conversation, and even Richard Thaler? Tell me. Priceless.
Tell me.
Priceless.
No Stupid Questions is part of the Freakonomics Radio Network,
which also includes Freakonomics Radio,
People I Mostly Admire,
and Freakonomics MD.
This episode was produced by me, Rebecca Lee Douglas. And now, here's a fact check of today's conversations.
In the first half of the episode,
Stephen explains that a bit, or binary digit, is the fundamental building block of all computing. This is true
for traditional computers, but quantum computers are built using qubits. Unlike bits, which can be
either on or off, represented by one or zero, qubits can function in what's called a superposition,
where they're both on and off at the same time, or somewhere on the spectrum between the two.
The capacity for quantum computers to depart from the binary system and operate in a gray area is what makes them so revolutionary.
In 2019, Google's quantum computer Sycamore, in 200 seconds, performed a mathematical calculation so complex that it would take the world's most powerful supercomputer, IBM's Summit, 10,000 years to do the same equation.
Later, Stephen and Angela discuss how they aspire to be less binary and more like the color spectrum of Crayola crayons. In particular,
Angela admires that Crayola offers both blue-green and green-blue. Upon investigation,
I found that the company does in fact have a shade called blue-green, but unfortunately,
they don't currently produce a hue named green-blue. Crayola does, however, provide sea-green and aquamarine, which both look pretty green-blue to me. And they do offer burnt sienna, which should make Angela happy
if she chooses to draw more tree trunks in the future. Finally, Angela says that shirts from
the activewear company Lululemon usually cost $120. This is false. The company's website currently lists a total of
191 women's tops, ranging from $24 to $98. But to be fair, the men's section of the website
does offer a three-pack of, quote, basic tees for $128. And Angela may have been thinking of the company's signature leggings, which do,
in fact, ring in at an average price of about $120. That's it for the Fact Check.
No Stupid Questions is produced by Freakonomics Radio and Stitcher.
Our staff includes Allison Craiglow, Greg Riffin, Eleanor Osborne, Joel Meyer, Trisha Bobita, Emma Terrell, Lyric Bowditch, and Jacob Clemente.
Our theme song is And She Was by Talking Heads.
Special thanks to David Byrne and Warner Chapel Music.
If you'd like to listen to the show ad-free, subscribe to Stitcher Premium.
You can also follow us on Twitter at NSQ underscore show and on Facebook
at NSQ show. If you have a question for a future episode, please email it to NSQ at Freakonomics.com.
And if you heard Steven or Angela reference a study, an expert, or a book that you'd like to
learn more about, you can check out Freakonomics.com slash NSQ,
where we link to all of the major references
that you heard about here today.
Thanks for listening.
What did you do with the nubs of the crayons
that got too small to color with?
You mean, did I melt them down into candles?
Correct answer.
The Freakonomics Radio Network.
The hidden side of everything.
Stitcher.